Michael Quinlan, Claire
Mayhew and Philip Bohle
THE GLOBAL EXPANSION OF
PRECARIOUS EMPLOYMENT, WORK DISORGANISATION AND OCCUPATIONAL HEALTH: A REVIEW
OF RECENT RESEARCH
International Journal of
Health Services, Vol 31 Number 2 - 2001
-
abstract
-
introduction
-
a review of recent research on the OHS effects
of precarious employment
-
regulatory problems, the emerging policy
response and new strategies
-
placing current problems in comparative
historical perspective
Abstract
The paper is divided into two principal sections. The first part of the
paper reviews a range of studies of the health effects of precarious employment
in industrialised societies undertaken over the last ten years. The part of the
paper examines methodological issues, findings and areas in need of further
research. Of the more than 50 published articles and monographs identified all
but a handful found precarious employment was associated with a deterioration
in occupational health and safety in terms of injury rates, hazard exposures or
worker (and manager) knowledge of OHS and regulatory responsibilities. It also
identifies a need by researchers to more clearly link the health effects to
particular business practices and neo-liberal policies and to explore the
regulatory implications of the growth of precarious employment. This section
also tries to draw some general conclusions as to how to conceptualise the
association between precarious employment and occupational health. The Second
section of the paper tries to place this research in a comparative historical
context. It is argued that extensive use of precarious employment is not
essentially new. It was a characteristic feature of most if not all
industrialised societies at an earlier period, namely the 19th and
first part of the 20th century. Without claiming the both phases are
identical, historical comparisons are instructive in terms of understanding
recent experiences and ways of addressing them. This section of the paper also
makes comparisons with the third world where the informal sector typically
accounts for over the half the workforce. Again, it is argued such comparisons
are instructive in indicating the consequences of a shift to more precarious
patterns of employment and disorganised work settings. Further, there is good
evidence that precarious employment is expanding in the third world. Growing
precarious employment in both industrialised and developing countries are not
coincidental but connected and the paper identifies a number of these
mechanisms that are impacting on workers’ health.
Introduction
This paper focuses on the
association between precarious employment and the health of workers although we
recognise that the expansion of contingent work arrangements can have wider
health effects for the community. For example, outsourcing maintenance in the
transport industry and healthcare can have serious consequences for commuters
and patients respectively. Equally, it is arguable that the low income, long
hours and production pressures on contingent workers such as self-employed
truck drivers or home-based workers (such as those sewing garments) can - in as
much as it effects nutrition, accommodation, healthcare and domestic relations
- have not inconsequential implications for the health and well-being of family
members.
Recent Research on the OHS effects of precarious employment
Methods
In the main we have confined
our review to refereed articles published by journals in the fields of
health/medicine, work sociology, work or health psychology, industrial
relations, management and law. We have also a number of research monographs
(most notably by French scholars) which are based on substantial empirical work
but for which we were aware of no journal publication. Although we have tried
to avoid double counting, we have included more than one publication based on
the same empirical data where each presents substantially new information or
analysis (including cases where a number of surveys are combined).
The survey does not include
studies that only consider the impact of organisational change on job
satisfaction. While job
satisfaction is relevant to worker health and well-being this literature is
vast, making meaningful comparisons difficult. Here we have chosen to focus on
studies that include other and generally more direct measures of health
effects, or measures of legal and other knowledge specifically tied to OHS. The
survey does include studies of OHS in small business. Small business has been
included for several reasons even though this literature seldom makes a
explicit connection to precarious employment. First, micro-small business in
particular can arguably be regarded as a form of precarious employment
(including many self-employed workers and subcontractors). Second, its growing
significance in terms of employment has been a direct consequence of
outsourcing/competitive tendering and organisational restructuring. Third,
small business tends to employ more than proportionate number of temporary,
part-time, home-based and other types of contingent workers than larger
enterprises (for the USA see Wiatrowski, 1994).
Insert Table 1: Summary of Published Research on the association between
precarious employment and occupational health and safety
Results and Discussion
The most immediate
observation that can be made is that, notwithstanding the wide array of
methodologies employed and diversity of countries where the research too place,
almost all studies find an association between precarious employment and a
negative indicator of OHS.
One area of omission in most
the research is a failure to explore the consequences of the expansion of
precarious employment for work/non-work relations. The growth of precarious
employment can effect the balance of work and non-work activities in a number
of ways. First, for particular categories of precarious workers, most notably
home-based workers and their self-employed, there is (as has always occurred
for women, see Messing), a progressive blurring between private and public
spheres of activity. Second, the job and income insecurities associated with
precarious employment, the excessive hours associated with some jobs (like
truck driving) or the incompatibility of specified work schedules with family
commitments (including part-time workers, see Dwyer, 1994) can impact on domestic
roles and relationships of workers.
Table 2: Risk Factors Associated
with Precarious Employment
Economic and Reward Factors
|
|
·
|
Competition/under‑bidding of tenders
|
·
|
Taskwork/payment by results
|
·
|
Iong hours
|
·
|
Under-qualification and Iack of resources
(ie like small business)
|
·
|
Off-loading high risk activities
|
Disorganisation
|
|
·
|
Ambiguity in rules, work practices
and procedures
|
·
|
Inter-group/inter-worker
communication
|
·
|
More complicated lines of management
control
|
·
|
Splintering of OHS management system
|
·
|
Inability of outsourced workers to
organise/protect themselves
|
Increased Likelihood of Regulatory
Failure
|
|
·
|
OHS laws focus on employees in large
enterprises
|
·
|
OHS agencies fail to develop adequate
support materials
|
·
|
OHS agencies fail to pursue
appropriate compliance strategies
|
·
|
Problematic coverage by labour
minimum standards laws
|
·
|
Problematic coverage by workers'
compensation
|
Of course this is a crude
typology (crude typologies can still be useful!) and there may be other ways of
conceptualising the link between precarious employment and OHS. One possibility
in this regard is the large and growing body of medical and psychological
research which has linked work organisation to health outcomes using Karasek’s
job strain model or some derivative of this. Measuring job demands on and the
decision latitude of precarious workers would seem to have real potential,
especially in terms of explaining health effects beyond traumatic injuries and
in debunking misleading legal interpretations of the degree of independence and
control exercised by most self-employed contractors. …Levels of control
Unfortunately, until
comparatively recently most studies using this model failed to differentiate
employment status or focused on full-time and relatively secure workers. A
study by Brisson et al (1998) did differentiate by employment status (ie
permanent/non-permanent) and found
More recently, a number of
researchers prominent in this area including Aronsson and Netterstrom have
already undertaken either new research on precarious employment or have
extended their earlier work into new studies which take explicit account of
this aspect (see Netterstrom’s study comparing CVD for outsourced and
non-outsourced bus drivers). Further, some researchers involved in the
Whitehall studies are beginning to look at this aspect while a growing interest
in management systems amongst US researchers involved in studying bus drivers
is indicative of a similar shift (see Landsbergis et al 1999).
Another protential link is the
body of research on new ‘production concepts’ (like just in time, lean
production) and methods of managing workers (such as business process
re-engineering, engineered standards). Unfortunately the bulk of research in
this area has focused on industries with still relative conventional employment
structures (such as automobile manufacturing) and has either ignored or made
only limited reference to the OHS outcomes of such systems (see Landsbergis et
al 1999). Equally, for their part OHS researchers have only recently begun to
look at management systems. One study to make the link
between precarious employment, new management methods of work organisation and
OHS is Wright and Lund’s (1996, 1998) studies of the introduction of engineered
standards into grocery warehousing in the USA and Australia. Their study shows
that the employment of temporary workers was an integral part of a new
intensified work system with these workers being used as rate-busters and
setting performance levels which NIOSH studies found to be unsustainable.
Unfortunately, the examination of the OHS effects is insufficient to be
included in Table 1 although their offers some important leads for future
research. precarious employment and the new Taylorism
(Wright & Lund on warehousing) and Toomingas et al on telecall centres and
work specialisation (see also Aronsson et al, 1994).
Professional, Institutional and Regulatory Effects
In addition to affecting
basic indicators of worker health, safety and well-being, it seems clear that
the growth of precarious employment also has a series of effects on various
groups of OHS professionals, institutions and regulatory apparatuses.
Unfortunately, until very recently these aspects went unrecognised or were
ignored by researchers. What evidence we do have indicates these effects
compound problems already identified and also make it increasingly difficult
for practitioners, policy-makers and others to manage them using conventional
devices. The remainder of this section will briefly summarise this evidence and
indicate a number of areas where further research is required.
The presence of contingent
workers can create problems for OHS professionals in a number of ways. For
example, the existence of large and volatile temporary workforce, including contractors
coming on and off-site, or workers employed at home and in other remote
locations will make it more difficult for OHS managers or professionals like
OHS medical practitioners and nurses to ensure adequate safety training and
induction. Similar logistical problems may arise in relation to pre-placement
medical examinations and surveillance, undertaking risk assessment of all work
processes and maintaining adequate injury, incident etc records – including
those required under legislation (Gyi et al, 1998; Morris, 1999:477). The
problems arise not simply from workforce volatility associated with precarious
employment but also an increase reporting problems identified by existing
research (Morris, 1999; Quinlan and Mayhew, 1999).
Effects on OHS Professions
It is now becoming clear
that the growth of precarious employment has implications for OHS practitioners
and professions such OHS manager, occupational physicians, ergonomists,
rehabilitation counsellors and occupational health service providers more
generally. Unfortunately, this area has been little research. However, a number
of effects can be identified.
First, change processes may
directly affect OHS services within an organisation where the OHS unit is
reduced, splintered or in other ways reorganised in tandem with downsizing,
devolution or other forms of restructuring by the employer concerned. In some
cases all or part of the OHS function (including rehabilitation) may be
outsourced.
Second, quite apart from
their own restructuring internal units and individuals primarily responsible
for managing OHS will need to address the challenges if not additional burden
of dealing with the morale etc problems of workforce reductions and loss of
experienced workers, the risks associated with an increase in temporary workers
or contractors to give but two examples. These problems will also impact on
outside OHS service providers as well as other firms and agencies dealing with
injured workers (such as insurers and rehabilitation providers). For example,
those involved in rehabilitation will need to confront issues of how to help a
injured worker employed on a temporary basis where the employer has no real
interest in their fate or future prospects. Even where OH services are mandated
as in parts of the EU, there coverage of smaller workplaces and firms has been
problematic and the growth of more disorganised work-settings is almost certain
to amplify problems of both coverage and the quality of service provided.
At the very least these
problems will present new and significant challenges. Some (see Gibson, 1999)
suggest OHS specialists and practitioners will need to develop new skills and
competencies if they are to exert an impact and retain their relevance. These
include a greater need to understand business strategies and integrated
management systems, to deal with special groups such as contractors and
home-based workers, to assess and respond to changes in technology, work
systems and workforce demographics; to simultaneously deal with long latency hazards
and a transient workforce and to involve themselves in other areas affecting
OHS such as collective bargaining.
Methodological Issues and Problems
One obvious methodological
question that these findings raise is why a serious deterioration in health
indices identified has not been apparent in official OHS statistics. There are
number of possible (and not necessarily mutually exclusive) reasons for this.
At the general level, it could be that the deterioration may have been masked
by an overall improvement in OHS due to inter-sectoral shifts in employment
(notably from manufacturing, mining and construction to the service sector). At
a more specific level, it could be suggested that the way OHS statistics are
constructed in most countries does not just ignore differences in employment
status but may actually disguise these effects (see below). Further, in some
countries the matching of OHS statistics with data on employment status is made
difficult because government statistical agencies have only recently tried to
identify the extent of these employment arrangements through irregular surveys.
Thus, data-matching is difficult and in the USA, if not elsewhere, this problem
is compounded by the arbitrarily narrow definition of contingent work and temporary
jobs used by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (see Quinlan and Mayhew, 1999). It
should also be noted that until recently researchers simply did not look for
these effects although when they did, as Foley’s (1998) study shows, a
significant effect was discernable.
It is also possible that
reporting effects have masked the deterioration. Official OHS statistics are
often based on workers’ compensation claims that are known to significantly
understate the actual incidence of occupational illness, including substantial
omissions in relations to disease, acute and chronic injuries. A growth in
precarious employment will almost certainly compound these omissions. For
example, identifying a disease related to occupational exposure becomes
immensely more difficult where a worker has held a series of relatively short
terms jobs in a diverse range of work-settings. In a similar vein retrospective
epidemiological studies will become more difficult because it is less likely
that an occupationally related disease will be recorded on a death certificate.
For workers having held a series of jobs it will even be difficult to record
‘usual occupation’ (a requirement for death certificates in the USA and other
countries) with any degree of accuracy. The problem is liable to be most acute
for male workers, given the already high error rate for working women whose
occupation is entered as ‘housewife’ (Zahm, 2000:443).
There is also a suspicion in
at least some countries that the gap between incidence and claims may have widened
over the past decade due to changes in workers’ compensation regimes, the
introduction of managed care etc. Hence, the apparent improvement in OHS
statistics may be, at least in part, an artefact of reporting. More to the
point, in many countries the expansion of precarious employment has meant an
increasing number of workers (like self-employed subcontractors) who are either
formally excluded from compensation coverage or subject to voluntary (rather
than compulsory) cover. For a much larger group cover is uncertain or workers
are reluctant to make claims for fear of interfering with income flows or
future employment prospects (Quinlan and Mayhew, 1999). Clearly, to make
meaningful comparisons using official data requires better knowledge of the
employment status and claims behaviour of particular categories of workers (say
between hospital-based nurses and those in nursing homes or home-based health
care). Available evidence indicates
those occupying precarious jobs are more reluctant to report injury, delay
reporting or only report severe injuries. This means that identified
associations may understate frequency or produce a bias towards serious injury
amongst the contingent group. A recent USA study (Meyer and Muntaner, 1999)
using compensation data found home-based health nurses/nursing aides
experienced fewer injuries than their counterparts in nursing homes, but more
than hospital-based staff and their claims also resulted in more lost time and
costs than both nursing home and hospital staff. Knowledge of reporting effects
as well as work practices may help to understand why home-care workers appear
to have more severe injury. Further, information on the employment status of
nursing home personnel might indicate whether there was under-reporting in relation
to this group (due to a higher level of temporary employment than hospital
staff). While it is impossible to indicate all the permutations here
researchers need to be aware of these issues in both constructing studies and,
equally importantly, interpreting their findings.
-
fragmented research using different
methodologies and different definitiions
-
reporting and measurement problems (in some
industries there is no comparitor)
-
problem with cohort studies where no cohort
-
limits/strengths with self-reported health
effects
-
ability of surveys to assess historical
changes, institutional and regulatory effects
It is important to put
criticisms of the methodological problems facing research into precarious
employment into context. Indirectly if not explicitly, this research has
highlighted some important methodological flaws in previous research. Research
into precarious employment is leading to a greater recognition of reporting
effects. This includes an increased questioning of the use of workers’ compensation-based
data – at least without considerable and explicit reservations. There is also
growing recognition that the health impacts of organisational downsizing may be
masked or complicated by the over-representation of older and less health
workers amongst those displaced and a reluctance of surviving workers to report
illness or take absence for fear this will endanger their job. It may also lead
to increased claims amongst those whose fate has already been decided.
Further, it is now
increasingly clear that the exclusion of temporary workers from the survey
population (based on a particular workplace, company or group of employers) – a
practice often at best only glibly acknowledged by researchers (usually on the
basis of inadequate medical records. See van Poppel et al, 1998) could
constitute a serious source of bias to any interpretation of OHS indices or
intervention measures designed to modify this or worker rehabilitation. While
it is acceptable, indeed useful, to express injury or disease incidence in
terms of equivalent full-time workers (requiring a recalculation where workers
are employed for shorter hours) the findings of research on precarious
employment indicate that dis-aggregated comparisons are also warranted. I am
also unaware as to whether similar conventions are devised where workers are
employed well-beyond the hours normally ascribed to full-time work. But even if
they were it is well known that excessive hours can pose particular risks.
Given this, and the clear connection between very long hours and some groups of
precarious workers (like long distance truck drivers, home-based garment makers
etc), there is another ground for dis-aggregating groups so any significant
disparity amongst them in terms of incidence can be clearly identified.
In some cases methodological
bias appears less accidental than a reflection of dominant managerial
interests. For example, it seems more than coincidental that while there are
relatively few studies on the health impacts of downsizing and other forms of
organisational restructuring (de-regulation, privatization etc) there is an
extensive psychological literature on interventions (like counselling, social
support etc) to moderate worker dissatisfaction and ‘non-compliant job
behaviour’ associated with these same practices or job insecurity more
generally (see Lim, 1997 – a study also based on MBA alumni which, as Platt et
al, 1998:23 point out is hardly representative of workers affected by labour
market change).
The growth of precarious
employment may also require modification of other research agendas, including
the growing bodies of research on the OHS implications of an ageing workforce,
and women’s OHS (where insufficient recognition is given to the fact that the
majority of women occupy contingent jobs). It should also cause us to question
the occupational focus and orientation of the extensive research shiftwork and
occupational stress. In both cases we would suggest researchers have tended to
focus on occupations that are unrepresentative of the workforce undertaking
shiftwork or at risk of occupational stress either in terms of the type of work
(this has been recognised) but also, and perhaps more importantly, in terms of
employment status. Virtually all the shiftwork and occupational stress literature
examines full-time workers in jobs that are presumed to be ongoing (although
the occupational stress literature is now examining downsizing). This can be
seen in the selection of occupations for studies. Even where, some popular
targets of shiftwork research, such as nurses, have experienced a significant
growth in casualisation, part-time employment and outsourcing, with rare
exceptions these changes have gone unrecognised. More important perhaps, we can
readily identify a number of industries such as hospitality and retailing that
employ substantial number of workers in shift arrangements and where many of
these hold part-time or temporary posts. In other industries involving
shiftwork, like road transport and mining, the use of contractors is already
widespread or is growing (depending on the countries involved) and
outsourcing/labour-hire arrangements is extending this to other areas (like
stevedoring, rail and air-transport). Even where there has been a significant
shift to casualisation, part-time work and outsourcing It is worth noting in passing that the
connection between ‘flag of convenience’ shipping has created a precariously
employed maritime workforce (fishermen are another precariously employed group
working non-standard hours) and similar trends are emerging in other sectors
(like airlines).
3.0 The Regulatory
Implications of Labour Market Changes
Overall, evidence is
fragmentary, especially when definitional and methodological issues are taken
into account (see Platt et al 1998 and Aronsson, 1998). Nevertheless, there are
increasing grounds for concern that the growth of precarious employment is
having an adverse effect on OHS in industrialised societies even if the extent
of the problem varies between countries. Most studies deal with injuries
although there is some evidence on disease (Netterstrom and Hanson, 1998).
There is also some evidence that the shift to precarious employment may
increase the risk of various forms of occupational violence (including
harassment) or at least make this issue more difficult to manage (Mayhew and
Quinlan, forthcoming). It should be
emphasised that these effects may be masked in official statistics because the
same labour market changes affect workers’ compensation/health insurance claims
data as well as other data sources (Quinlan, 1999, Quinlan and Mayhew, 1999).
These changes also pose direct and indirect challenges to prevailing regulatory
regimes concerned with safeguarding workers and it is to this that attention
will now turn.
Historically, the OHS
regulatory regimes of most industrialised countries focused on full-time
employees in large workplaces. While laws purported to cover all workers little
compliance activity was directed at smaller workplaces, subcontractors or more
casualised forms of employment. The same applied to the provision of
preventative services, with the impact of the European Framework Directive
being mainly confined to large firms (Walters, 1997:267-8). From the late 1980s
government agencies in the EU, North America and Australia increasingly
recognised that that lifting OHS performance in small firms required
specialised materials and strategies (OSHA, 1997; Lamm, 1995; Hassle and
Limborg, 1997; and Mayhew et al, 1997). However, only in exceptional cases like
Denmark was small business comprehensively incorporated into compliance
programs (Jensen, 1996). In the USA, Wiatrowski (1994:34) reports that
establishments with 10 or fewer employees are not required to keep OHS records
and are not subject to inspections. Even in countries without formal
exemptions, inspectoral activity continues to focus on large workplaces. Risks
to younger workers have also begun to attract recent attention, backed in some
cases by community group and union initiatives (see Ontario Ministry of Labour,
1997). Articles 6 and 7 of the European Directive on the Protection of Young
People at Work (94/33/EC) require employers to take account of young workers,
lack of experience, awareness and maturity when assessing risks and allocating
tasks. Parents of school-age children are also to be informed about risk
assessment outcomes and control measures.
However, the best that can be said is that implementation of these
provisions by member countries has varied widely.
The OHS problems of
outsourcing have evoked a generally muted response. In a number of countries
OHS agencies produced employer guidance material on managing contractors (see
Victorian WorkCover Authority, 1996 and Health and Safety Executive, 1997).
These initiatives are still exceptional and often restricted to a particular
industry like construction or local government. Some agencies have made
increasing use of the general duty provisions in OHS legislation to prosecute
employers, major contractors and labour hire agencies for failing to provide a
safe system of work for outsourced workers. This activity has had a limited
effect and in areas like road transport safety enforcement continues to ignore
subcontracting (Mayhew and Quinlan, 1997b). In the EU recent efforts to extend
the Working Time Directive (93/104/EC) to include road transport (that employs
around 3.5 million workers) were opposed by employers, partly on the grounds
that many drivers were self-employed. An existing European Regulation (3820/85)
stipulated maximum driving hours for both employed and self-employed drivers
but this did not cover activities like loading and unloading that often formed
an important part of driver’s tasks (European Commission, 1997). Following
considerable consultation involving the European Trades Union Congress (ETUC)
and the Union of Industrial and Employer’s Confederations (UNICE), the European
Commission proposed to guarantee rest-periods and limit maximum annual hours
for all mobile workers. UNICE opposed this measure, arguing all member states
already had some form of working time regulation and advocating a
voluntary/non-binding sector-specific approach. Yet, as the 1997 White Paper
had noted, there was no consistency in member-state regulations (almost
certainly exacerbated by variations in compliance) and the competitive
advantages derived from perpetuating such differences warranted a
Community-wide approach.
In some countries at least
the regulatory apparatus dealing with subcontracting is either ambiguous, not
enforced or actually discourages major contractors from taking an overriding
responsibility for OHS (see Rebitzer, 1995:56). It is also a moot point as to
whether OHS agency initiatives are being overwhelmed by the promotion of
competitive tendering/outsourcing as part of the microeconomic reform agenda
being pursued in many industrialised countries. In Britain and Australia, for
instance, OHS problems were largely ignored during the development of
competitive tendering/outsourcing programs (Tombs, 1996:321 and Industry
Commission, 1995:189). Tombs (1996) concludes that while the conservative
Thatcher government abandoned a direct assault on OHS regulation its pursuit of
privatisation/competitive tendering and other de-regulationist policies
undermined the ability of the OHS agency to carry out its mandated functions.
There has also been limited
recognition of the need for new regulations and compliance strategies on
part-time and temporary workers. In 1990 the European Commission adopted a
draft Directive on the protection of health and safety for part-time, temporary
and seasonal workers. It is unclear how far this measure has been implemented
and there have been no comparable steps in countries like Australia with
comparatively high levels of part-time and casual labour. In 1997 the Italian
Ministry of Labour and Social Insurance prepared a report (Synthesis, 1997) on
the relationship between temporary work, ‘accident’ prevention and security.
The report (1997:20-2) identified a number of familiar risk factors (isolation,
poor communication and training, disorganisation and inexperience) and called
for a significant re-fashioning of regulatory intervention (not simply the laws
directly governing OHS) and reconsideration of EU Directives (such as
91/383/EU). Looking at Britain and France, the report (1997:3) argued French
law demonstrated the only way to protect temporary workers was to ensure parity
of treatment between this group and permanent workers. It therefore advocated
efforts to bring the submerged world of precarious employment into the
mainstream of labour regulation. Other proposals included the identification of
jobs requiring special surveillance measures, inclusion of OHS in various
levels of education/training and a separate law establishing norms of health
and security protection for ‘unusual’ workers. Most of these proposals have yet
to be implemented although in June 1997 a bill regulating temporary agency
labour was introduced into the Italian parliament.
Governments have been
equally slow to respond to the growth of home-based work and telework (de
Vries, 1996:69-105). Both the European Union and several member countries have
commissioned preliminary reports on the OHS problems and regulatory issues
raised by telework and home-based work (Huuhtanen, 1997; de Vries, 1996; and
Westberg, 1997). In the Netherlands, the Dutch Working Environment Act covers
employed but not self-employed teleworkers (de Vries, 1996:91). Regulatory
coverage means little without compliance activity and inspecting home-based
workplaces remains the logistical nightmare it was 100 years ago (Mayhew and
Quinlan 1999). The European Commission has called on member states to ratify
the 1996 ILO convention on homeworking. More recent Commission documents have
identified the difficulty of using conventional regulatory solutions in
relation to small business and contingent workers (European Agency for Safety
and Health at Work, 1998:12,35).
Overall, governments and
international agencies have only recently responded to the challenges posed by
changing labour market structures (for a discussion on Europe see Walters,
1996b). A recent ILO report on contract labour contained only a brief reference
to OHS (Egger, 1997:8). Neo-liberal governments in Canada and elsewhere have
even used the growth of small business to justify a more de-regulated approach
to OHS, arguing that existing regulation is being rendered irrelevant (Witmer,
1997). In Britain a Health and Safety Executive (1996) discussion paper on the
regulatory implications of labour market restructuring rejected the wholesale
exemption of self-employed workers from OHS laws (although change in
construction regulations had this effect. Mayhew and Quinlan, 1997a:199-200)
but also failed to recommend initiatives on contingent workers. In the USA a
recent paper by Rosentock (1998) on emerging research issues for NIOSH
identified problems associated with an aging and more diverse workforce, more
unconventional working hours and changes to work organisation but there seems
little prospect of regulatory initiatives on contingent work. Although most
governments have ignored the cost/benefit implications of labour market
restructuring. However, a report prepared for the Netherlands Ministry of
Social Affairs and Employment (van Waarden et al 1997) raised the spectre of a
serious deterioration in OHS performance and increased costs unless regulation
was re-fashioned to address the growth of contingent workers and other
workplace changes.
Labour market changes pose
problems for worker and union input into OHS regulation. In many industrialised
countries unions make an important if not always apparent contribution to OHS.
Unions are pivotal to the collective labour law regimes that establish a
baseline of employment conditions (wages, hours etc) – and these minimum standards
affect OHS – as well the framework for workers raising and negotiating safety
issues without fear of losing their job. They also exert influence through
political lobbying on OHS laws, representing injured workers in compensation
proceedings and providing logistical support for the worker involvement
mechanisms (representatives and committees) established under OHS laws or
industry agreements. Reforms to OHS legislation in many advanced industrialised
societies (especially northern Europe and Australia) since the 1970s were
predicated on a collaborative approach based on informed employees and a high
level of union organisation. Participatory mechanisms such employee health and
safety representatives and joint workplace committees usually entailed establishment
procedures/requirements which meant they were unlikely to occur in small or
non-unionised workplaces. Even where laws grant participatory rights to
non-unionists this has proved problematic in practice (James and Walters,
1997:35-50).
Union membership is
significantly lower amongst contingent workers such as the self-employed, those
in small business, part-time and temporary workers (Lettau, 1995 and Campbell
1996) and the growth of precarious employment has arguably contributed to a
decline in union density experienced by many industrialised countries
(exceptions include Sweden and Austria).
Falling union membership levels have, in turn, weakened worker input
into OHS regulation and this gap has not been filled by alternative forms of
employee representation (Walters, 1996a). Rather, in countries like Canada, New
Zealand, Australia and the UK the declining scope for union involvement in OHS
has been exacerbated by changes to labour law restricting union rights to enter
workplaces, recruit or bargain. There is evidence that the combination of
labour market change and decentralised or de-collectivist industrial relations
regimes have facilitated work intensification and an erosion of OHS standards
(see Nichols, 1997), and these effects are liable to be most pronounced amongst
contingent workers with little bargaining power.
Finally, (see Quinlan and
Mayhew, forthcoming), labour market changes can pose a particular challenge to
more elaborate OHS management systems/internal control regimes that have become
increasingly popular amongst OHS policy-makers in the last decade. The growth
of precarious forms of employment and smaller more volatile employment units
can weaken these developments by:
·
reducing the number of workers employed by large
organisations where these systems are most applicable;
·
increasing the number of workers in isolated or
inadequately planned work-settings and encouraging competition amongst workers;
·
making it more difficult to address insidious health
risks of exposure to hazardous substances;
·
creating enclaves of contingent workers in large
organisations whose incorporation in OHS management/internal control systems
will be problematic; and
·
making it more difficult for unions to monitor or
vet systems performance
At the same time it could be
argued that OHSMS provide a vehicle for meeting these very challenges,
especially where it is embedded in a pervasive regulatory framework. Countries,
which would seem to meet these criteria are Norway and Sweden with their strong
level of union organisation and mandated OHSMS. It was for this very reason
that a recent inquiry into OHS regulation in my state of New South Wales sent a
delegation to Sweden and Norway in 1998 to explore these aspects with local
experts. In the case of Sweden there is the added interest of examining to what
extent the system of regional safety representatives has helped to meet these
challenges. Unfortunately, as far as I am aware there has been far more
research assessing internal control in Norway than in Sweden.
4.0 A Proactive Regulatory Response
While the fracturing of
labour markets appears to be a general trend the extent of regulatory problems
in any given country will vary according the level of casualisation,
outsourcing etc, government policies and the nature of employment legislation.
However, at the risk of over-generalisation a number of regulatory responses
can be identified.
1. Altering the form and implementation of existing OHS regulatory regimes
This represents the most obvious
starting point for a regulatory response. Indeed, in many industrialised
countries such initiatives have already commenced. These initiatives include the development of
new codes or regulations relating subcontracting/labour hire, casual or young
workers and small business together with changes to enforcement methods and
targeting (such as prosecutions directed at major contractors). This approach
has merit, especially where legislative contains general duty provisions that
can be used to develop of pervasive web of regulatory responsibilities and one
which also targets those parties with the greatest capacity to affect OHS
outcomes (such as major contractors rather than subcontractors). There is also
some possibility to use overlapping webs of contractual obligation (such as
those found in franchising arrangements) to strengthen regulatory controls (see
Johnstone, 1999). Nevertheless, this response suffers from a number of
problems.
First, it is largely reactive
rather proactive, seeking to remedy problems as they are identified and
arguably lagging well behind in a game of ‘catch-up’ that cannot be won. It
fails to address the economic pressures on some groups of workers to not report
injury, the churning problems of workplaces with high labour turnover, the
turnover of contractors and small business or the capacity of medium to large
firms to use business law to re-engineer their legal identity. It also fails to
address the forces driving the shift to precarious employment, notably
neo-liberal policies of promoting competition (competitive tendering,
outsourcing, corporatisation/privatisation, removal of trade and transport
barriers, purchaser/provider models of service delivery etc). Even where these
occur within particular countries or economic blocks with an apparently strong
and comprehensive framework of regulatory protection there is a basic imbalance
in regulatory impact. That is changes to business and commercial arrangements
will tend to overwhelm corresponding responses from OHS regulators. In the EU
for example the first cabotage regulation on road transport introduced on 1
July 1998, enabling any lorry to drive anywhere in the EU (including domestic
or intra-country trips on an as yet undefined ‘occasional’ basis) has set a
number of significant changes in motion. This includes a growth in the number
of self-employed drivers, relocation of transport companies to countries with
more ‘sympathetic’ regulatory regimes, pressure on employed drivers to accept
wage cuts in order keep their jobs, the growth of legal and illegal employment
practices (including engaging eastern European drivers at ‘flag of convenience
wage rates), a regional refocusing of transport activities to meet the new
competitive environment and pressure on union membership and inter-union competition
for jobs. These changes in turn have flow through effects onto OHS (in terms of
driving practices, drug use etc) that OHS regulators and unions in countries
with superior working conditions and OHS standards will have difficulty
addressing especially. Governments have resisted defining ‘occasional’ for fear
of sacrificing jobs to other member states. Further, the fact that there are
significant disparities in the level of implementation (both formal and in
terms of actual enforcement activities) amongst EU members (see Lampinen and
Uusikyla, 1998) will tend to compound these effects in high compliance
countries like Sweden. The entry of new EU members from Eastern Europe is
almost certain to exacerbate this situation. Where, as with NAFTA, there is even
less recognition of the need to safeguard employment standards in conjunction
with new trade and competition policies the effects are liable to be even more
profound.
Second, to be even partially
effective this approach requires the commitment of considerable resources at a
time where public expenditure on OHS regulation is stagnant or declining in
many industrialised countries (Walters, 1997:266-7). Some categories of
contingent workers, notably home-based workers and child-labour (which has
re-emerged as an issue in industrialised countries in Europe, the USA and
Australasia. See ETUC, 1998), exist in a shadow-land of informal and often
clandestine employment. Identifying and locating these workers represents a
daunting exercise and attempts to address their OHS problems without other
forms of regulatory intervention are unlikely to prove effective (Kinney, 1993;
NIOSH, 1996 and Mayhew and Quinlan, 1999). For example, Australian studies of
clothing outworkers and road transport workers indicated that the primary
source of OHS risk was the combination of low pay/incentive payments and
excessive hours of work. In the clothing industry several state governments are
working on strategies to locate primary OHS responsibility with retailers (who
tend to drive the outsourcing of work), together with a system for registering
outworkers and ensuring they work according to minimum wage and working hours
standards (including union access to records). In road transport there is a
complex interchange of separate road transport, OHS and industrial relations
laws and mooted solutions include a similar registration system for all
drivers, requiring freight forwarding companies to prepare written work plans
and the appointment of inspectors empowered to enforce all three bodies of law.
In construction, where similar problems exist, one response has been the
development of a memorandum of understanding amongst 20 major firms as to the
minimum requirements to be met by subcontractors incorporated into a package
known as subbie-pack. However, this only applies to commercial buildings not
the housing sector where subcontracting is even more pervasive. The responses
have strengths in addressing the contours of the use of contingent labour that
are specific to an industry. At the same time, there is a real question as to
the feasibility of developing and implementing such packages for every
industry.
Third, implicit in the foregoing
is the observation that the growth of precarious forms of employment do not
simply alter OHS regimes. They can also often effect union density (since
precariously employed workers, especially self-employed and home-based workers,
are often more difficult to recruit and service) and industrial relations
(collective negotiations and the ability to enforce minimum labour standards).
Hence, a strategy tied to OHS regulation alone is unlikely to succeed.
2. More over-arching regulatory solutions
A more comprehensive and cost
effective solution would to modify regulatory regimes in a way that discourage
contingent forms of employment or (the French approach) to try and ensure
precariously employed workers receive exactly the same employment conditions
(this is also liable to discourage contingent work arrangements). This could
involve:
·
Changes to labour regulation to minimise any gap in
conditions between precarious and non-precarious workers. To be effective it
would need to deal with actual rather than formal disparities in entitlements
and this is likely to prove difficult;
·
Changes to business law to restrict the ability of
firms to reconfigure their legal form in order to evade statutory employment
requirements (probably more a problem in English speaking countries such as the
USA and Australia);
·
Changes to taxation law to remove incentives for
employers to re-designate workers as self-employed contractors rather than
employees; and
·
Ensuring regulatory liability (environment, OHS,
labour standards etc) focuses on the top of the ‘food chain’ (i.e. large
corporations) irrespective of how these organisations choose to arrange the
production of goods and services.
Most if not all of these measures
are liable to prove controversial as they directly confront the twin policy
mantras of globalisation and microeconomic reform. Yet apparently radical steps
can be supported on the grounds that OHS has not only been ignored in the
debate over microeconomic reform (Purse, 1997), but these policies (including
privatisation) are compounding the economic, social and human costs of
occupational injury and disease.
Placing
the debate in a comparative historical perspective
In order to understand the
current shift to precarious employment in advanced industrial societies and its
implications for OHS it is essential to place it in a comparative historical
context. There are two clear parallels. First, a substantial level of what
would now be seen as precarious employment (such casual labourers) and
disorganised work settings were characteristic feature of most, if not all,
industrial societies around a century ago. Second, insecure employment and a
large informal sector is a characteristic feature, indeed dominating, feature
of so-called newly industrialising countries (third world remains a more
accurate descriptor and we will continue to use it henceforth).
These parallels have not
gone completely unrecognised. For example, in reviewing Thomas Legge’s legacy
to modern occupational health in Britain, Harrington (1999:2,4) notes hazardous
exposures to employees in small metal workshops similar if not identical to
those that concerned Legge 100 years ago could still be found. Indeed, small to
medium enterprises were a major focus of current Health and Safety Executive
activity. In looking to future challenges, Harrington (1999:5) notes the role
of multinational corporations in establishing global production and
distribution networks, and the very polarised consequences this can have for
OHS in third world countries (ranging from first world OHS management systems
to highly exploitative wages and dangerous working conditions). He also points
to critical changes employment within industrialised countries, especially the
growth of short term contracts, job instability, the bipolar trend to both
part-time work and longer hours, as well as the shift to smaller workplaces and
home-based work. While Harrington (1999:5) makes reference to the impact
management ‘delayering’ and ‘downsizing’, technology is seen as a driving force
in the growth of home-based work and there is no suggestion that these trends
are integrally tied to changing business practices and regulatory policies.
Apart from small workplaces, Harrington cannot see that there are other
parallels with the late 19th/early 20th century – namely
significant levels of insecure employment or that the growth of home-based work
can, to some degree, be viewed as the re-emergence of a very old employment
practice. Indeed, occupational health/medical texts of the time, as well as
government inquiries in Britain, Australia and elsewhere make extensive and
detailed reference to the problems posed by insecure and ‘sweated’ (often via
piecework payment systems) employment of women, men and children, especially
home-based work (not to mention long hours). Telecommuting is only one part of
the recent growth in home-based work documented in a number of industrialised
countries. Some areas of growth (like home-based garment making) in north
America and Australia amount to little more than the re-emergence of an old
practice (including middlemen and child labour. Mayhew and Quinlan, 1999). Even
in new areas (like home-based telemarketing) the payment system (simple
contract, piecework or bonus systems) and other employment practices are
essentially similar to older forms of home-based work.
In a similar vein, a number
of writers have noted that the incidence of work-related injury (and to a
lesser extent disease) being experienced in newly industrialising or third
world countries countries are similar to those found in advanced industrial
societies during their phase of rapid industrialisation. One such writer is
LaDoue (1992:224) who attributes this to the limited education, training and
skills of workers, old and poorly designed workplaces, an absense of safety
protection equipment and under-resourced regulatory agencies. Likewise others
have argued that the transfer of manufacturing (and to a lesser extent
services) to third world countries as well as increasing foreign capital
penetration of commodity production has entailed a migration of occupational
hazards and hazardous processes. It many instances it has entailed a shift to
forms of work organisation and working conditions that are well below minimum
regulated standards (on employment, OHS and environment) in the first world.
This literature often refers to high unemployment/little job security, poor
bargaining power of third world workers, suppression of unions and weak forms
of protective legislation (usually in little detail and ignoring workers
compensation altogether). However, the direct parallels with the expanding
precarious workforce in industrialised countries is seldom made let alone
explored. It is referred to in some recent research on OHS within the informal
sector in third world countries such as Zimbabwe and Brazil (see Santana, 1997
and Loewensen, 1998,1999). However, again these parallels have failed to
attract serious attention from those examining precarious employment in the
industrialised world, including the connections between the processes that
expanding precarious employment in both the first and third world.
Overall, the observations
are useful (and need to be made more often) but the accompanying analysis is
either entirely missing or under-developed. In the remainder of this paper we
shall try to address this by doing three things. First, to look at the
historical parallels in more detail. Second, to look at the factors driving the
renewed growth of precarious employment in industrialised countries. Third, to
examine the processes expanding precarious employment in third world countries
and, where possible, to identify evidence as to its consequences for OHS.
Rediscovering the lost
history of precarious employment and OHS in industrialised countries
Insecure or fluctuating
employment, small workshops, home-based work, self-employment and other
arrangements that would now be labelled as contingent work or precarious
employment were widespread even pervasive in most if not all industrialised
countries in the 19th and early 20th century. A number of
occupations, including sweated trades like tailoring (with a combination of
irregular employment, fierce competition for work and low remuneration)
attracted the attention of early writers on occupational medicine, official
inquiries (such as those preceding factory legislation), inspectors reports and
other observers. Since precarious employment was so widespread it was often not
seen as a remarkable or distinguishing characteristic. Nevertheless, a number
of early writers on capital/labour relations clearly demonstrate its
importance. In Industrial Democracy
(1914 but first published in 1897) Sidney and Beatrice Webb devote a separate
chapter to continuity of employment and union struggles over this, as well as
discussing the ramifications of casual work, subcontracting, outwork etc at
many other points. Similarly Atkins and Laswell’s Labour Attitudes and Problems (1924) has a chapter on casual
labourers as well as separate discussions on home-based work, disorganisation
in the labour market and irregular employment. Further, it is not difficult to
find contemporary observers making a connection between insecure employment or
overwork and OHS. Interestingly many observers also refer to one or more of the
three features of precarious employment identified in much contemporary
literature as having adverse effects on OHS, namely economic/reward pressures,
disorganised work and ineffectual regulatory protection. To briefly illustrate
these points we will look at several categories of workers, beginning with
home-based garment workers.
Elizabeth Rogers, a
home-based needlewoman gave evidence to the 1892 South Australian Royal
Commission on Shops and Factories as to how the subcontracting system led to
excessive competition for work, long hours, low wages and endangered health.
I
could mention six (young girls) now whose lives are worked through working so
hard at the shirt trade. It is hard work to make a dozen shirts in a day and
some have to work, oh, so hard. One girl is at home now, and is being attended
by the doctor. She had to make a dozen shirts in a day to get her wages (Minutes
of Evidence cited in Williams, 1997:37).
Alice Milne, another
shirtmaker and witness to the same inquiry, later became an inspector and in a
1904 report on sweating advocated regulatory intervention to:
…prevent
a few in the struggle for crumbs to become a means of not only making their own
lot worse, but also dragging others down to the same level. That is what the
small unregistered workplaces and homeworkers are doing for the general body of
wage-earners in the clothing trade in Adelaide (cited in Williams, 1997:39).
Writing two years earlier, a
British writer (Ballantyne, 1902:98-99) cited a number of strikingly similar
cases and, highlighting institutional and regulatory problems, argued home-work
was:
…practically
the No Man’s Land of the industrial world. Here treads not the foot of the
labour agitator, for home-workers are largely composed of “casuals” – dreary
phantoms, who come and go, whence and whither no man can tell, and no
organising sectretary of any trade union, however enterprising, would waste
time or effort inducing them to join its ranks. Each worker is a sort of
industrial Ishmael, working only for his or her hand.
Nor
has the home-worker been much better off in respect of Government protection.
For while the factory and workshop hand has had the conditions of her work
regulated by law, the home-worker…has been left outside the protecting pale of
the Factory Act.
At the same time, Ballantyne
(1902:99) stressed that far from being an anachronism or aberration, home-work
was a logical extension of the factory-work, a subcontracting mechanism for
meeting fluctuating demand and other contingencies. In describing payment and
hours Ballantyne (1902:101-2) not only reinforces the issue of regulatory
failure and disorganised work settings but also point to critical externalities
affecting the whole community:
The
evidence collected in respect of out-work by expert investigators in these and
other cases seem to prove conclusively that is usually accompanied by very low
wages, inordinately long and irregular hours, and distressingly insanitary
conditions… And there is double ground for interference here, in that the
making of clothing and other articles for public use in insanitary dwellings is
not only a danger to workers themselves, but also to the public generally…
Out-workers
are often used as a lever for reducing the rate of wages. They are not
restricted by any law to a specified number of hours per day as in factories,
and they are often found working from early morning till late at night… It may
be interesting to note that a large number of outworkers met with during these
inquiries were in receipt of parochial relief, although they were working
full-time for their employers.
Essentially identical
comments about the subcontracting system and excessive hours of home-workers
and small employers can be found in government inquiries carried in Britain,
Australia, the USA and probably elsewhere over the preceding 30 years if not
earlier (for reports of British inquiries in the 1860s see Hutchins and
Harrison, 1926:164. See also Aves, 1908:12).
Through these observers we
can also find a recurring link drawn between home-based and some other types of
insecure work with the employment of children by parents to supplement meagre
family earnings (McMillan, 1902:90-7; Piddington, 1912 appendices A & B).
Thus, for example, New South Wales Factory Inspector Annie Duncan told the 1912
Piddington Royal Commission (Appendix A:liv) about the use of children as part
of family based production units as well as the diversity of working
conditions, concluding:
The
conditions of the rooms is as various as the type of workers, but the essential
note struck everywhere amongst those who are dependent on the work for their
living was “drive”.
In the USA the situation was
similar a decade later, with an investigation by the Pennslyvania Department of
Labor citing cases of children as young as five working at home and stating:
Nineteen
percent (209) of visits to 1113 families revealed 401 cases of child labor, an
average of two children in each household. Child labor is even more prevalent
than this percentage indicates for women are apt to conceal from an
investigator the industrial work of children since they know the public
sentiment looks with disfavor upon the gainful employment of children under
fourteen years of age (cited in Atkins and Lasswell, 1924:151).
Although the situation
subsequently improved we are now witnessing a deterioration in tandem with the
re-emergence of widespread home or small sweatshop-based garment making in
industrialised countries along with a growth of home-based employment more
generally. At the turn of the next
century the regulation of OHS in home-based work remains largely ineffective in
many countries, beyond the scope of over-taxed inspectorates even where they
have rights of entry. Our recent study of home-based garment production in
Australia (Mayhew and Quinlan, 1999) found a remarkably reminiscent pattern of
exploitive subcontracting and middlemen ‘sweaters’, long hours under pressure,
low payments, injury rates three times factory-based workers (none received
workers’ compensation). It also revealed cramped and inadequately ventilated
work areas, widespread child-labour (as young as seven years) and other
externalities (including tax evasion and social security payments). While
home-based work represents a shadow-land where exploitation and child labour
can flourish it is by no means the only area where contemporary instances of
child labour can be found (see for example the use of children in immigrant
family groups of fruit and vegetable pickers in the southern USA).
Home-based garment makers
were the exemplar for policy debates over ‘sweated labour’ encompassing a much
wider array of workers that can be found in Britain, Australia, Canada and many
other countries from the 1880s into the first decades of the 20th
century. ‘Sweating’ referred to the process whereby groups of workers received
remuneration so low that the hardest and longest duration of work secured to
barest existence. The sub-letting tasks - what is now called
outsourcing/subcontracting - was seen to be a leading causal factor in
‘sweating’ (Aves, 1908:79). A report by Ernest Aves (1908) to the British
parliament on the operation of wages boards/concialiation and arbitration in
Australia and New Zealand highlighted the importance establishing effective
minimum labour standards by regulation to address ‘sweating’ and it social,
economic and health consequences. One hundred years later a debate over the establishment
and enforcement of minimum labour standards has re-emerged in a number of
industrialised countries in response to growth of precarious employment and the
weakening of pre-existing legislative protections in the name of enhancing
labour market ‘flexibility’. It is of some little irony that these pre-existing
laws were in part a response to the ‘sweating’ debate. However, the sweating
debate is also a powerful reminder that the protection afforded by OHS
legislation is predicated on a broader basis of institutional and regulatory
controls on wages, hours of work and the rights of workers to organise. What is
also of some interest in terms of our purpose here is the explicit link Aves
(1908:69-71) makes between ‘sweating’ and disorganised and exploitive work
arrangements. In a section entitled ‘Disorganisation in Industry’ Aves argued
that rather than seeing ‘sweating’ in terms of employer morality, attention
needed to focus on structures and processes, namely the economic competition
and dependency associated with sub-letting led to under-cutting of payment and
other exploitive practices. Aves (1908:71) concluded that regulation was a
necessary solution (and Australasian experience with wages boards indicated
regulation worked) and given that there was ‘no clear line of demarcation
between the organised and the disorganised trades’ there was no reason why this
form of regulatory intervention should not apply to all.
In addition to home-based
workers it is also worth briefly considering the casual/temporary workers and
particularly those employed as longshoremen, stevedoring or dock workers. A
dedicated dock labour force emerged in the 19th century (previously
seamen carried out this activity). Dock-workers were employed of casual basis
with men being selected for work by foremen on an arbitrary, demeaning and
potential corrupt basis known under various labels including the bull system
(named after the ‘bulls’ who set the pace for other workers). Competition for
selection and a desire, once selected, to maximise the chance of future work
was conducive to low and irregular pay, intense work rates, disorganised work
practices and an authoritarian labour management regime (Webb and Webb,
1914:433). From the late 1880s onwards the direct and indirect effects of these
employment practices on living conditions and health were the subject of some
recognition and public inquiry in countries like Britain. Inquiries revealed
that low and irregular earnings translated into malnutrition (for both workers
and their families) and an inability to budget, cramped and unsanitary
accommodation. The combination of overwork and the hiring system often left
older workers unable to obtain any employment (Court, 1965:304-12). Poverty and
the casual system often meant inadequately clothed workers handling dangerous
cargoes (like soda ash, treated hides or frozen meat) or exposed to cold and
damp (Tull, 198715-29 and Webb and Webb, 1914:588). Even some dock company
managers were prepared to concede this and to point out that hunger-induced
exhaustion often forced workers to leave a job prior to its completion:
The
poor fellows are miserably clad, scarcely with a boot on their foot…and they
cannot run, their boots would not permit them…These poor men come to work
without a farthing in their pockets…and by four o’clock their strength is
utterly gone; they pay themselves off: it is absolute necessity which compels
them… (cited in Webb and Webb, 1914:588).
The heavy and intensive
nature of dock work, the rushing induced by the bull-system and the
disorganisation associated with turnover/instability in terms of work gangs,
management inattention to work processes and other consequences of
casualisation contributed to a high rate of injury. Evidence of these
connections is easier to obtain for the early 20th century than the
19th century when inquiries appear to have spent more time
describing living conditions and the struggle for work than the work process
itself. While the very casual nature of employment made data collection
difficult the evidence we have for injury rates amongst dock-workers in
countries like Australia place it amongst the most dangerous vocations in the
first part of the 20th century (see Tull, 1987:23-26).
Available evidence makes it
clear that dock work was not conducive to longevity. Ogle’s analysis of deaths
amongst males aged 45 to 55 years reported to the UK Registrar General’s Office
in 1890-92 found dock/wharf labourers had the third highest death rate (at
40.71 per thousand) of the 40 occupations measured, just behind pottery workers
and well ahead of chimney sweeps and miners (cited in Wohl, 1983:279-81).
Casual employment of dock
workers lasted well into the 20th century in many countries and we
can therefore find more contemporary accounts of its effects on health. In
1942, for example, a specialist physician named McQueen undertook an
examination of 130 Australian wharf labourers for the Stevedoring Industry
Commission that identified the long term effects of these employment practices,
exacerbated by the Great Depression. Admitting he expected to find malingerers
or men disabled by alcohol, McQueen instead found men prematurely aged and
seriously disabled by their work and concluded:
Their
endless search for the infrequent job which would keep them and their families
from the precarious borderline of malnutrition had taken its devastating toll.
The feverish high tension work performed when the job is secured in order to
ensure its repetition had been paid for at the shocking high price of premature
old age and physical calamity (cited in Nelson, 1957:119).
It is worth noting that the
subsequent de-casualisation of the industry had little to do with technology
(predating containerisation, roll-on/roll-off and other major changes in
Australia and other countries with which we familiar) and a lot more to do with
union pressure and resulting institutional/regulatory changes. Equally,
employer efforts since the 1980s to re-casualise the industry have relied on
the managerial mantras of globalisation and labour market flexibility. Indeed,
the only explicit evidence of technological facilitation was employer’s
capacity to ‘secretly’ fly strike-breakers to train in Dubai in preparation for
the 1997/98 maritime dispute in Australia and, more recently, a global terminal
operator establishing a ‘flying dockers’ unit (ITF Circular
No.295/D.70/SS.55/1999).
Our discussion has barely
scratched the surface of potential comparisons between employment arrangements
a century ago and many of those increasingly associated with the misleadingly
labelled ‘new economy’. Many other industries, issues and outcomes are worthy
of further exploration. For example, some though by no means all of the
supposedly new forms of labour flexibility and management practices actually
represent very old forms work intensification, with obvious examples including
pyramid subcontracting and home-based work. More detailed comparisons would be
useful in identifying exactly what is new about the contingent work
arrangements that emerged in the last decades of the 20th century.
Equally, both contemporary reports and later research on industrial societies a
century ago identify the problem of injury and disease reporting amongst
economically vulnerable workers afraid of losing their job. Some research, such
as Harrison’s (1995:20-41) study of the match-making industry in 19th
century Britain, point to active measures by employers and health professionals
to conceal the problem. A century later we are in the process of rediscovering
that there are reporting problems in relations to vulnerable workers such as
self-employed subcontractors those employed casually or in high turnover or
disorganised work-settings. Labour leasing provides opportunities to conceal or
re-badge injured workers. Further, the downsizing and outsourcing have affected
the provision of occupational health services both directly and indirectly,
reversing some of the gains in terms of identification and treatment built on
permanent employment in large workplaces. Thus, downsizing and outsourcing of
OHS has opportunities for direct workplace inspections by occupational
physicians as well as imposing subtle pressure on subcontracted physicians not
to ‘make waves’ that might jeopardise renewal of their contract. Another avenue
for further research relates to outcomes for workers. In The Hygiene Diseases and Mortality of Occupations Arlidge
(1892:133) identified an abnormally high suicide rate amongst small
self-employed traders. Some recent studies of isolated groups of contingent
workers (see Thebuad Mony, 1999 and Mayhew 1999) have also pointed to a
possible connection with abnormally high suicide rates which may be worthy of
further investigation.
If nothing else, comparisons
with OHS amongst workers who are precariously employed or disorganised
work-settings a century ago should disavow any expressions of surprise at the
consequences of the more recent trend to these forms of work arrangement. It
should also drive home what is being lost in conjunction with the dismantling
of institutional and regulatory safeguards.
As far as we are aware, there is no compelling comprehensive account of
the shift away from precarious employment most industrialised countries during
the first half of the 20th century. It is clear from what we have
said already the process was not a direct or even accidental by-product of
technology and did not occur uniformly across all occupations. We can point to
a number of possible and probable explanatory factors. One possible factor was
the introduction of mass production that enhanced the advantages of directly
hired and ongoing employment although the Japanese case show extensive
subcontracting was still compatible with mass production. Another set of
factors was immigration, tariff, cabotage and other trade policies restricting
product and labour market competition. A number of the latter, as well as other
institutional and regulatory changes, were connected either directly or
indirectly to the rising industrial and political influence of organised
labour. The most apparent examples of the latter include the growth of unions,
collective bargaining and the common rule (preventing workers from
under-cutting each other) as well as specific union de-casualisation/permanency
and anti subcontracting campaigns. Other examples include changed employment
practices away from using casual or contract workers (as in the case of
labourers employed by local government, road and sewerage authorities). Further
examples, include the enactment of laws restricting child labour, regulating factories
and other workplaces (including home-based work), establishing minimum wages
and other labour standards (including specifically invoking these in government
contracts and providing workers’ compensation. Finally, the development of a
pervasive welfare network in relation to the provision of healthcare (excluding
the USA), social security in case of sickness/disability or unemployment and
old-age pensions clearly reduced pressure of persons otherwise forced to eke
out a living under the most disadvantageous circumstances.
Overall, it appears the
decline of precarious employment/growth of permanent employment in
industrialised societies during the course of 20th century to the
point where the latter not the former was seen as typical (always an exaggeration,
especially for women) was not an inevitable outcome of market forces or
technology. Rather, it was an outcome shaped by regulatory/institutional
pressures. Given this, we are sceptical about contentions that the present
trend is economically determined, inevitably and irreversible. We are not
suggesting that there are no important differences between the periods (the
welfare state, for instance, while battered remains in place). Nevertheless,
reference to an earlier era of precarious employment provides powerful portents
of the socially dislocating consequences of existing trends and even some clues
as to how these problems might be addressed.
Re-inventing the 19th
century: The re-introduction of precarious employment to advanced industrial
societies and OHS
The current dominant policy
discourse over much of the industrialised world would have us believe flexible
employment structures are an essential component of the ‘new’ global economy.
However, neo-liberal economics and the policies currently promoted under this
banner do not constitute the only, inevitable or ‘real’ discourse or
understanding of socio-economic relationships. Rather, it is an arrangement
that serves particular interest groups and seeks to justify the expropriation
of wealth, power and humanity from others by portraying this process as
inexorable and tied to objectified ‘market forces’. In essence, the explanation
is and has to be ideology recast as science. This means the growth of
precarious employment should be seen as the outcome of specific and reversible
actions by key interests groups, most notably large (often multinational)
capital and complicit organs of the economic profession, financial community,
management consultants and government.
The growth of precarious
employment is connected to a number of international developments that impact
on both developed and so-called developing countries. Indeed, these processes
are connected. Policies in the developed world are contributing to the growth
of precarious employment in the developed and developing countries.
While this paper cannot
provide a comprehensive explanation of the growth of precarious employment in
industrialised countries it is important to identify a number of arguably
critical factors and, provide a few brief examples, of how these impact on OHS.
For convenience we will group these factors under four headings although all
overlap and arguably flow out the neo-liberal economic policy agenda (the
precise transmission mechanisms are important but beyond the scope of analysis
here).
1)
Changes to management employment, production
and service delivery practices in the private and public sector that are design
to cut operating costs or enhance shareholder value have directly and
indirectly promoted a shift to precarious employment. The tools of achieving
this have gone under a range of labels including corporatisation,
privatization, outsourcing, downsizing/organisational restructuring,
competitive tendering and managed care/case management. Practices like
outsourcing almost always amount to a direct transfer of workers to a more
precarious position (even when subcontract workers are employees) and
associated effects including work intensification may also contribute to
additional workforce volatility (including burnout). The effect of downsizing
on precarious employment is also unambiguous. However, as the health service
industry shows, precarious employment (including home-care workers) has also
grown more subtly through policies of de-institutionalisation and case management
(often ultimately designed to achieve greater through-put in the use of
hospital beds). It is worth noting that large management consulting firms have
acted as one key transmission belt for these ideas.
2)
Neo-liberal ideas have also exerted a critical
influence on government revenue and expenditure policies including reductions
in direct income tax (and increases in regressive sales and service taxes), the
pursuit of balanced budgets and critical changes to government transfers to the
poor. These changes have promoted precarious employment in a number of ways.
The environment of budgetary constraint has placed pressure of government
agencies to cut costs and embrace the ‘new managerialism’ which has commonly
resulted in cuts to staffing (one of the few ways of ‘measuring’ the
productivity in the provision of complex services), competitive
tendering/outsourcing and so on. These pressures have been intensified by
demands that agencies should deliver productivity bonuses over time – something
normally measured in terms of reduced costs/expenditure or direct cuts to the
workforce. In some countries at least, the appointment of private sector
managers and consultants and changes to senior management appointment and
remuneration structures have reinforced this process. The winding back of welfare
regimes (cutting or tightening access to unemployment relief, workfare/work for
the dole, a return to prison labour) and cuts to workers’ compensation
benefits/entitlements, public health, disability and other pensions in many
industrialised countries over the past decade or more have had important
effects. These include lowering the effective wage/employment floor and
increasing the number of workers forced to take the most menial, low paid and
insecure jobs.
3)
In many though by no means all industrialised
countries the growing influence of neo-liberal ideas has also been manifested
in alterations to industrial relations regimes, weakening union input and
collective regulation (if only through decentralisation but at worst through
individual employment contracts and altering employment relationships by
manipulating legal boundaries). In Australia recent legislative changes have
removed the formal right of unions to include limits of casual or part-time
workers in awards or collective agreements and have introduced options for
non-union and individual agreements that employers have used to promote more
contingent work arrangements. n New Zealand the changes have been even more
extreme. Even in countries where such changes have not occurred the push for
more decentralised collective bargaining/enterprise agreements (for example, by
the government agency responsible for productivity and competition in Sweden)
will make more difficult for unions to limit precarious employment or protect
workers occupying such jobs. Examples of
the deliberate altering of legal forms include the growing use of labour
leasing and employer attempts to re-designate their workers associates or
contractors rather than employees (as highlighted by the recent Microsoft case
in the USA). In Australia and the USA if not elsewhere batteries of law firms
have facilitated this process, assisting with the manipulation of legal forms
and providing ongoing advice to counter the response of regulators. Again, we would note that in least some
countries with which we are familiar neo-liberal competition/productivity
agencies in a number of countries have become increasingly active in
transmitting and implementing these ideas.
4)
Finally, it is important to acknowledge the
implications for precarious employment of business interests increasingly
capturing domestic and global policy agendas. In essence this has amounted to
the increasing subordination of labour and related standards to the investment
and trade interests of business, and with it a push for more ‘flexible’
workforce. It can be noted that the world’s two leading regional trade blocks,
NAFTA and the European Union have both endorsed promoting numerical flexibility
in the labour market and neither has sought to restrict the growth of temporary
employment (Vosko, 1998). Unlike NAFTA the EU has made some attempt to regulate
these arrangements, although - leaving aside the efforts of several member
countries, most notably France – the effectiveness of these measures is open to
question.
At the global
level, bodies involved in this process include the International Monetary Fund
(whose impact has been most direct on third world countries, see below) and the
OECD which has continually pushed for labour market flexibility. Perhaps the
most explicit attempt to subordinating labour to the trade and investment
interests was the Multilateral Agreement on Investment (MAI). The Business and
Industry Advisory Committee (representing some of the world’s largest transnational
corporations) promoted the MAI to the OECD and 29 OECD member countries spent
three years negotiating its adoption. In 1998 negotiations lapsed in the face
of mounting international protests and French government opposition although a
year later the World Trade Organisation was considering a new version despite
explicit opposition from developing countries including India (Bridges Weekly Trade News Digest 3(4)
February 1999 cited in Ranald, 1999). The World Trade Organisation has already
been active in promoting trade arrangements and government policies that
encourage the growth of precarious employment in both developed and developing
countries, most recently in the service sector – the largest and fastest
growing area of employment in developed countries. Thus, it has pressed for the
removal of monopoly arrangements or other restrictions in postal and courier
services and the removal of cabotage and other labour restrictions on land and
maritime transport (WTO, 1998a). It has also advocated the freer international
movement of labour (or what it labelled as natural persons) in distribution,
environmental health and social services (WTO 1998b,c&d). For example, a
background paper on distribution argued:
Given
the high labour intensity of distribution (especially in retailing), the sector
is affected by limitations on the movement of natural persons. Nationality requirements for staff prevent
firms from minimizing labour costs through international recruitment. Residency requirements for managers and directors
de facto disadvantage foreign
suppliers even when the requirements are imposed on all distributors. Immigration policy, visa restrictions, and
levies and charges for social security also impact on the sector (WTO
1998c:10).
In a similar vein, a background paper on
health services argued:
the most significant benefits from
trade are unlikely to arise from the construction and operation of hospitals,
etc., but their staffing with more skilled, more efficient and/or less costly
personnel than might be available on the domestic labour market (WTO,
1998d:18).
In background
note devoted entirely to ‘natural persons’ the WTO (1998e) secretariat
developed its views on the advantages of freeing up international labour
movements, including temporary migration, to meet short-term exigencies and
long term labour shortages. It is important to observe that evidence on
projected shortages was limited to a narrow band of occupations (most notably
information technology) and the paper effectively conceded that the major shift
of labour would be from developing to developed countries. In other words, the
rationale for the policy is less than demonstrable except in terms of altering
the supply situation and bargaining power of service sector labour in developed
countries.
In terms of the
international movement of labour, business groups within particular countries
or trading blocks have mounted essentially analogous campaigns to those of the
WTO. In Australia, for example, – the Business Council of Australia – the major
organ of big business – has led a campaign to re-introduced higher levels of
net migration (and achieving bipartisan political support) and reverse a
discernible trend towards historically smaller intakes. As in Europe, the case
for immigration is supported by reference to the age ‘time-bomb’ (ie an ageing
workforce) and skill shortages. These contentions mask an array of critical
assumptions, not the least of which is the high level of unemployment, not to
mention under-employment, already prevailing in much of the European Union and
Australia.
A few examples highlight the
OHS implications of the purportedly neutral neo-liberal policies and practices
just identified. In Australia, the implications of the impact of competitive
tendering policies on government agencies was highlighted in mid 1990s when one
state government introduced legislation requiring local government authorities
to open up at least half of their work activities to competitive tender.
Leaving aside the downsizing and work intensification that resulted, it soon
became clear that local governments could not manage contractor safety (for
which they remained legally responsible) and the government was obliged to
produce a special guide on contractor OHS management for this sector.
Another example of the
implications of competition policies, this time also involving the removal of
international ‘trade-barriers’ can be seen in the introduction of the 1998
European road transport cabotage regulation.
Insourcing and labour hire
(legge 34)
New production networks, old
forms of employment and dependency, and OHS in developing countries
International investment/subcontracting networks, the migration of jobs
and hazardous work organisaton
Much of the shift of
production and industries from developed to developing countries is a direct
consequence of policies pursued by corporate capital. As LaDou (1992:223) has
observed foreign firms account for most investment in manufacturing in
developing countries and their decisions are based on implicit calculations
about the lower costs of labour, health (including workers’ compensation) and
environmental infrastructure. What needs to be added is that these investment
flows often entail elaborate subcontracting networks rather investment in
‘independent’ entities. This shift can effectively entail a movement of these
activities to more disorganised work settings with a contingent workforce. In
some instances third world countries have become centres for hazardous
activities such as the breaking of ships in India. It can also involve a quite
deliberate attempts to evade a regulatory controls and achieve a cheaper
solution even though a technically superior and safer method for undertaking
this task exists (as in the case where used lead-acid batteries are exported to
India rather than being recycled locally). In both cases the workers involved
are employed on a piecework or incentive basis lacking security, set hours or
even the most minimal conditions. In short, what is involved here is not simply
a shift of employment but also a change to work organisation and jobs.
Outsourcing of production
and service delivery occurs at both a national and international level and
indeed the two processes may occur simultaneously and result from similar pressures.
For example, the development of global production networks and the reduction of
tariff barriers in the developed world relating to toys, clothing, textile, and
footwear etc has facilitate firms in developed countries relocating production
activities to developing countries. Direct employees of factories in developing
countries receive wage rates, OHS and other labour standards far below those
for comparable workers in developed countries. Further, these companies use
subcontracting networks of suppliers to obtain components and, as in developed
countries, workers employed by these subcontractors experience working
conditions inferior to those found in the parent factory. This subcontracting
not only cuts labour costs but also helps to evade ethical codes on product
production developed by retailers in the USA and other industrialised
countries). The result is a complex international web of subcontracting where
commercial exchanges are closely articulated but the corresponding social
relations of production and ethical responsibilities are disarticulated or
obscured. Thus, parents in Europe
purchase soccer balls for their children that have been stitched by children of
the same age or younger in Asia (where the piece rates take no account of age
and family pressures drive children to work. Legge, 2000) and unions made
similar allegations were in relation to rugby balls used for the 1999 Rugby
World Cup. Equally, their counterparts in Australia buy the multinational brand
footballs or cheap wooden picture frames produced the same way.
As has been noted for the
clothing industry (Mayhew and Quinlan, 1999) the combination of competition
from third world imports and retailer concentration/pressure to reduce costs in
developed countries then puts pressure on remaining domestic producers. This
leads to increasing insecure employment marked by job losses, factory closures,
more flexible and intensified work arrangements in factories as well as the
growth of outsourcing to smaller factories including backyard/illegal operators
and home-based workers (and the re-emergence of child labour in family
production units). This crudely exploitive apparatus may include an elaborate
network of pyramid subcontracting with as many as seven stages between the
retailer and the often immigrant woman or child who actually sews the garment.
Pyramid subcontracting
establishes a descending pattern of dependency and work intensity that can be
identified in far more technologically sophisticated industries such as car
manufacturing. Moreover, subcontracting is more than just a means of evading
employment standards etc in the core firm but also a means of transmitting
social relations of production as defined by discipline and quality (Rutherford
et al, 1996) and re-configuring power relationships in ways that may have
serious consequences for OHS. Outsourcing has become a means whereby
multinational firms can direct investment, production and marketing activities
on a global level and scale with a minimum of directly-employed workers and a
number of stages in the supply chain that distance and obscure the conditions
of those ultimately making the product (Legge, 2000:34). In several areas like toy, clothing and footwear manufacturing
serious incidents (like the fire at a Kader International in Thailand in 1993)
as well as campaigns by child labour/worker defence or human rights groups in
first world countries (like the Clean Clothes campaign in the European Union)
and third world countries (like the Hong Kong-based Coalition for the Charter
on the Safe Production of Toys) have exposed these inter-linkages and brought
consumer pressure to bear on multinational producers and retailers. However, it
is fair to say these dedicated efforts only address some of the harmful
subcontracting networks and their impact even in these areas has been limited.
Some organisations have been able to hide behind ‘holding firms’ that obscure
their links to production and supply network. Responses to criticism include
public assurances that the firm meets all employment and OHS standards of the
host country (hardly the point given the low level where these are set and the
even lower level of enforcement activity).
Another increasingly common
response is for multinational suppliers and retailers to establish ethical
codes of conduct meant to apply to all their dealings. The problem with these
voluntary codes is that they are largely symbolic, seldom being accompanied by
vigorous monitoring and enforcement (for evidence of these problems see Bureau of
International Labor Affairs, 1996). Code compliance remains outside the public domain
except in rare instances – instances that tend to reinforce questions about the
efficacy of these measures. For example, an internal inspection report
by Nike found workers at a subcontractor’s factory near Ho Chi Min city,
Vietnam were exposed to carcinogens (in some parts of the plant exposure
exceeded the local legal standard 177 times) and 77% of the workforce suffered
respiratory problems (Safety News
December 1997). The employees worked a 65 hour week for $US10. While the hours
aspect may not have breached local legislative standards the consequences of
prolonged hours for exposure to hazardous substances, fatigue and other OHS
risks are probably at least profound as the breaches just mentioned. Further,
half-hearted attempts to enforce voluntary codes may simply lead to more
extensive stages of pyramid subcontracting of dangerous or highly exploitive
activities.
Increasingly complex
patterns of global subcontracting also present significant problems for OHS
regulators. In the third world regulators operate in a framework where
governments are acutely sensitive to threats of relocation and evasion. In
1996, for example, Thai factories owned by the Austrian-based Eden group producing
clothing for Walt Disney were accused of widespread breaches of OHS standards
and subcontracting work to firms breaking child labour laws (South China Morning Post 28 September
1996). When the Thai Ministry of Labour ordered the closure of the printing
section due to hazardous chemicals the company responded by moving machinery
and equipment to a subcontractor, leaving 200 workers without jobs. While it
would be more effective to target the economic drivers, namely the firm at the
peak of the outsourcing pyramid, the jurisdiction of OHS regulators in
developed countries is confined to their own borders. In other words, global
subcontracting creates effective gaps in regulating employment and OHS
standards. Attempts at co-ordinating standards via the International Labour
Organisation have proved largely ineffective especially in a context where the
World Trade Organisation (WTO) is delivering judgements on the movement of
goods, services and labour that threaten existing labour standards (see below)
and efforts to incorporate minimum labour and OHS standards in WTO trade agreements has been fiercely
resisted by an alliance of third world and some developed countries (such as
the UK and Australia).
The precise configuration of
outsourcing (like that described in relation to garment manufacturing) will
vary from industry to industry (for example the incentive to retain some
domestic production in the fashion component of the clothing industry may not
apply to toy production). It may also vary from region to region (for example,
access to immigrant workers including illegal immigrants) may facilitate some
highly exploitive forms of outsourcing or home-based work. However, we may find
essentially parallel process apply across a range of industries as the ‘race to
the bottom’ on labour conditions ratchets its way through various productive
and service markets globally.
The restructuring of production in developing countries
The shift of production and
to a lesser extent service activities (like software development in India) to
developing countries might be seen as contributing to a growth of precarious
employment in developed countries but not necessarily increasing and perhaps
even reducing the extent of these types of work arrangement (usually referred
to as informal employment) in developing countries. However, while such work
arrangements were already for more extensive in developing countries it appears
that the informal employment is expanding in these countries. Even in some of
the more industrialised developing countries like Brazil the informal sector is
seen to account for more than half the workforce.
The restructuring of trade
via trade agreements, free trade zones and cuts to protection, as well as
increasing multinational penetration, capital flows/patterns of lending,
financial dependency/colonisation and intervention in policy by international
agencies (most notably the IMF) have resulted in changes to the organisation of
production which to some extent mirror but also amplify effects seen in the
developed world. For example, the opening of the Mexican economy to
international trade was accompanied by the government privatising many of its
productive holdings, including the sugar industry where it led to a wholesale
re-organisation of production (Lemez-Ruiz, 1999). This included breaking down
old styles of paternalistic management, mill closures and reducing union
influence. Rising job insecurity went in tandem with a dramatic increase in the
pace of work, intrusive forms of performance measurement and declining real
incomes. The result has been heightened worker insecurity and sacrificing
safety for continued employment that has also been identified in connection
with privatisation and other forms of organisational restructuring in developed
countries. Lemez-Ruiz (1999:60) also identifies pressure on local government
for further concessions to retain employment in the region as well as the
impact of changed use of pesticides and cane burning practices on the health of
both animals and workers in the neighbouring cattle industry.
- add
Asian crisis and economic restructuring in S Korea
The undercutting of international OHS standards and agencies
The same interest groups
that are pressing for more flexible labour markets world wide - meaning labour
markets which facilitate precarious or contingent work arrangements by reducing
the extent of regulatory or collective worker intervention to circumscribe
employer choice over the duration, hours, accrued benefits and termination
conditions etc of jobs – are also looking to reduce or manipulate other
regulatory controls that effect the profitability of conducting business.
As Castleman (1999:61-4) has
observed, a number of large corporations pursue double standards in relation to
occupational and environmental health in terms of the production, export and
use of particular materials such as asbestos. This included the ongoing
manufacture of asbestos products and use of asbestos components (for the
automobile industry) in countries like Brazil by French and US companies which
had been obliged to cease such practices in developed countries. It also
involves the use of bodies like the World Trade Organisation to try and slow if
not defeat moves a growing number of countries to ban asbestos products as well
as the attempted manipulation of international agencies like the ILO and WHO
responsible for developing standards on exposure to hazardous substances as
well as scientific and professional bodies like ICOH. Significant disparities
in OHS standards world wide, and weakening existing international standards,
provides a climate more conducive for contingent work arrangements in both
developed and developing countries.
5.0 Avenues
for Further Research
1. Identifying and Measuring the Extent of the Impact of Precarious
Employment on OHS
-
labour hire agencies, international contracting networks in particular
industries, temporary workers
-
role of work organisation and management practices
2. Researching Regulatory Effects
and Externalities
Thus far, most research has
focused on trying to assess the impact of precarious employment on the
conventional indices of occupational illness (injury and disease rates etc).
Although most researchers are aware that these changes also have effects on the
conventional apparatuses used to regulate injury/disease prevention,
compensation and rehabilitation these aspects have been little explored in
detail. On the preventative side Johnstone (1999) has argued the growth of
precarious employment undermines existing paradigms of OHS regulation and
raises critical issues about the intersection of OHS law with other bodies of
law, especially business law. The precise indices will depend, of course, on
nature of business and employment law within particular countries.
There is also some evidence
internationally that the growth of precarious employment is having profound
effects on the coverage and administration of workers’ compensation and
rehabilitation regimes (see Quinlan and Mayhew, 1999). It has been argued that
this growth is reducing both the formal and effective coverage of workers’
compensation regimes and adversely affecting worker knowledge of their
entitlements and their capacity to make claims. It creates additional
administrative problems for agencies in terms of determining coverage,
establishing a work-relationship to injury or disease, identifying the relevant
employer (especially in the case of leased or subcontract workers). Declining
job security also has critical implications for both short-term and (more especially)
longer term rehabilitation.
3. Better Identifying the Causal
links in terms of Government Policies and Business Practices
No comments:
Post a Comment